terça-feira, 23 de janeiro de 2007
Pro-poor growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insights from 14 countries
Executive summary:
Pro-poor growth in the 1990s:
Lessons and insights from 14 countries 1
Part 1: Poverty, growth and inequality 14
the 14 countries 19
Basic trends in poverty, growth and inequality 21
the relationships between poverty, growth and inequality 25
Growth was good for the poor 26
Growth does not explain all the variation in poverty 28
notes 32
Part 2: Increasing the participation of poor people in growth 34
Making agricultural activities more productive for poor households 36
Factors affecting growth and agricultural earnings 38
agricultural growth and poverty reduction 41
how did poor households participate in agricultural growth? 43
helping poor households take advantage of nonagricultural
and urban employment opportunities 52
Factors affecting the growth of nonagricultural earnings 53
nonagricultural growth and poverty reduction 54
how did poor households participate in nonagricultural growth? 57
notes 69
Part 3: Pro-poor growth strategies that reflect country conditions 72
Policy lessons for pro-poor growth 74
Country conditions affect pro-poor growth priorities 75
Country analysis of growth-poverty linkages 76
areas for further research 77
iv Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
annex 1: ten lines of enquiry for country analysis 80
annex 2: Interpreting growth elasticities of poverty—a difficult task 81
Statistical appendixes 83
Bibliography 96
Boxes
1.1 two definitions of pro-poor growth 19
1.2 Macroeconomic stabilization and growth in the 14 countries 24
2.1 Public transfers and pro-poor growth 37
2.2 hIV/aIDS hits the labor force in Zambia and Uganda 40
2.3 agricultural growth reduces poverty 42
2.4 agricultural subsidies in India—who benefits and at what cost? 51
2.5 Informal employment and poverty reduction—it can be quite effective, but not always 56
2.6 Investment climate indicators 59
2.7 Remittances reduced poverty but in some countries also increased inequality 67
2.8 targeting public investment in Vietnam 68
Figures
1 Growth reduces poverty 2
1.1 the majority of the poor lived in rural areas in the early 1990s, except in Brazil 22
1.2 Urban poverty fell more rapidly than rural poverty except in Burkina Faso and
countries that experienced no growth… 22
1.3 … but poverty reduction occurred mostly in rural areas, except in those countries
with high urbanization (Brazil, el Salvador and Bolivia) and with growth
concentrated mainly in urban areas (Senegal) 23
1.4 Growth recovered in the 1990s 23
1.5 Inequality down for 6—up for 8 26
1.6 Growth reduces poverty 27
1.7 Consumption by the poor generally grew slower than average consumption 27
1.8 Growth and inequality components of poverty reduction—
complementing or offsetting 29
1.9 national averages in Ghana mask significant regional variation in the contributions
of growth and inequality to poverty reduction 29
1.10 Changes in growth and inequality are related 30
1.11 Significant poverty reduction but rising inequality for countries growing faster
than 3 percent a year 31
2.1 trends in agriculture productivity reveal 3 country groups 38
2.2 Production of cash crops rising in three african countries—food crops declining 40
2.3 Cocoa, coffee and cotton prices up, then down 41
2.4 nonagricultural growth was five times that of agriculture 53
2.5 Urbanization was a driver of nonagricultural growth 54
2.6 Faster income growth for those with secondary education in rural Bangladesh 61
2.7 Faster income growth for those with postsecondary education in urban Bangladesh 62
2.8 Most african countries still have not achieved universal primary education 63
2.9 Secondary enrollments remain low in both the asian and especially the african countries 63
2.10 Spending on secondary education for the poorest quintile rose in Ghana,
Vietnam and Indonesia but fell in Uganda 64
2.11 non-farm income became a disequalizing force in the late 1990s in rural Bangladesh 67
2.12 Public spending on infrastructure declined in africa 69
Tables
1.1 trends for the 14 countries 21
2.1 Decomposing poverty reduction in Ghana and Uganda by sector of activity 43
2.2 Many agricultural producers in Sub-Saharan africa lack market access,
even in areas of good potential 46
2.3 In Zambia expansion into cash crops was mainly by medium-scale farmers 47
Map
1.1 the 14 case countries 20
Contents v
this report was prepared under the auspices of the operationalizing
Pro-Poor Growth research program co-sponsored by agence Française
de Développement (aFD), Bundesministerium für wirtschaftliche
Zusammenarbeit und entwicklung (BMZ), kreditanstalt für
wiederaufbau entwicklungsbank (kfw), Deutsche Gesellschaft für
technische Zusammenarbeit (GtZ), Department for International
Development (DFID) and the world Bank.
the report was drafted by a team led by louise Cord and comprising
Binayak Sen (Bangladesh), Stephan klasen, Melanie Grosse, Rainer
thiele, Jann lay, Julius Spatz and Manfred wiebelt (Bolivia), naércio
Menezes-Filho and ligia Vasconcellos (Brazil), Michel Grimm and
Isabel Gunther (Burkina Faso), José Marques (el Salvador), andrew
Mckay and ernest aryeetey (Ghana), timothy Besley, Robin Burgess
and Berta esteve-Volart (India), Peter timmer (Indonesia), Radu
Gheorghiu, wojciech Paczynski, artur Radziwill, agnieszka Sowa,
Manuela Stanculescu, Irena topinska, Geomina turlea and Mateusz
walewski (Romania), Jean-Paul azam, Magueye Dia, Clarence tsimpo
and Quentin wodon (Senegal), John a. okidi, Sarah Ssewanyana,
lawrence Bategeka and Fred Muhumuza (Uganda), thomas Bonschab
and Rainer klump (Vietnam), James thurlow and Peter wobst
(Zambia), Derek Byerlee, Chris Jackson, Peter timmer and Radhika
nayak (agriculture and rural development), Stephan klasen (Gender),
omar azfar (Institutions), Sabine Bernabè and Gorana krstic´ (labor
Markets), humberto lopez (Macroeconomics), Vera wilhelm and
Ignacio Fiestas (Public expenditures). Communications Development
Inc., led by Bruce Ross-larson, assisted the team in conceptualizing
the report and was responsible for the book’s design, editing and
production.
the members of the oPPG research program include Christian Rogg,
Manu Manthri, Mandy Chatha, tom Crowards, will Gargent (DFID),
Christian Flamant, François Pacquement, Jean Marc Chataigner and
Jacky amprou (aFD), Birgit Pickel and Daniel alker (BMZ), Ulrike
Acknowledgments
Part 1: Poverty, Growth and inequaLity vii
Maenner, hartmut Janus and Julius Spatz (GtZ), annette langhammer
and henning andresen (kfw) and louise Cord, humberto lopez,
Ignacio Fiestas and Sabine Bernabè (world Bank).
the work was carried out under the direction of adrian wood
(DFID), luca Barbone, Sudhir Shetty and Danny leipziger (world
Bank).
the study reflects comments received from a workshop with the
country authors in Frankfurt (June 2004), and from workshops in
london (December 2004) and washington (February 2005) with the
authors of the sectoral papers, the core donor team and world Bank
and DFID staff. these workshops also included academics, nGo
representatives and representatives of other donor agencies. the study
also reflects feedback from participants of the world Bank’s PReM
Conference sessions, Equity and Pro-Poor Growth and Making Growth
Pro-Poor: Cases and Policies, organized jointly with the 2006 World
Development Report team.
Many others provided helpful comments, including Gary Fields
(Cornell University), Peter timmer (Center for Global Development),
alan Gelb, Daniela Gressani, tamar Manuelyan atinc, John Page,
edgardo Campos and Martin Ravallion (world Bank), nancy Birdsall
(Center for Global Development), lionel Demery and John toye
(Consultants), Max everest-Phillips and arjan de haan (DFID) and
Marc Raffinot (aFD-DIal).
nelly obias and esteban hernandez were responsible for processing
the manuscript and provided invaluable assistance to the team during
its preparation.
the operationalizing Pro-Poor Growth (oPPG) program was initiated
in 2003 by the aFD, BMZ (kFw/GtZ), DFID and the world Bank to
better understand the options for policymakers to increase the impact of
growth on poverty reduction and how they vary depending on policies
and country conditions. the goal was not to provide a specific policy
framework for pro-poor growth. It was to explore the channels for the
poor to participate in growth and the country context and initial conditions
affecting the efficiency of growth in reducing poverty.
the oPPG work adds to the literature by drawing on 14 country case
studies: Bangladesh, Bolivia, Brazil, Burkina Faso, el Salvador, Ghana,
India, Indonesia, Romania, Senegal, tunisia, Uganda, Vietnam and
Zambia. the countries had at least two household surveys in the 1990s
and early 2000s that offered comparable methodologies, consumption
aggregates and poverty lines. the country studies systematically analyzed
the distributional pattern of growth and how it was affected by
country policies and conditions, thus overcoming some of the wellknown
shortcomings of cross-country econometrics.
the case studies shared a common empirical methodology to analyze
the distributional impact of growth that built on Ravallion (2004a).
the studies looked at four broad policy areas and how each affected the
ability of poor people to participate in growth: the macro framework
and the composition of growth; agriculture and nonfarm income; labor
markets and employment; and public expenditure policies. the role of
gender and institutions in affecting policies and their outcomes were
addressed as cross-cutting themes. these four areas were not meant to
be comprehensive. access to financial markets and health services, as
well as voice and empowerment, were not explicitly addressed in each
case study, though they were mentioned in some.
to draw out the key lessons, seven thematic papers were prepared
covering: macro stability and pro-poor growth, growth and inequality,
labor markets and employment, agriculture, public expenditures, institutions
and gender. the thematic papers draw on the case studies, other
Preface
Part 1: Poverty, Growth and inequaLity ix
literature covering related themes in the 14 countries, and in some cases
additional empirical work generally on a subset of the 14 countries. this
report provides an overarching synthesis of all this work.
In looking at the distributional impact of growth on the poor, the
study adopts an income-based metric of poverty reduction (based on
national poverty lines). (the role of nonincome dimensions in increasing
the impact of growth on the poor and helping households to escape
poverty will also be covered by an ongoing world Bank study that will
be executed in FY06–07 titled, “Moving out of Poverty.” the oeCD
PoVnet group also commissioned a study on the nonincome dimensions
of pro-poor growth.) But institutions and nonincome dimensions
of poverty are considered highly relevant determinants of the distributional
impact of growth on income poverty and are discussed where
relevant. It is thus primarily focused on the first Millennium Development
Goal for the reduction of income poverty. the country cases and
the synthesis paper focus on the 1990s, but overall poverty, growth and
inequality trends of the decade are viewed, where possible, within the
countries’ broader historical experience. Partly data-driven, the limitation
on the 1990s reflects the relatively limited time horizon available to
many policymakers. It also allows us to investigate how the economic
developments of the 1990s may have affected the relationships between
poverty, growth and inequality.
2 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
Policymakers who seek to accelerate growth in the incomes of poor
people, and thus reduce overall poverty, would be well advised to implement
policies that enable their countries to achieve a higher rate of
overall growth. evidence from the 14 countries in this study confirms
that the pace of overall economic growth is the main factor that determines
how quickly poverty declines. a successful pro-poor growth
strategy should have, at its core, measures to achieve sustained and
rapid economic growth. these include macroeconomic stability, welldefined
property rights, a good investment climate, an attractive incentive
framework, well-functioning factor markets and broad access to
infrastructure and education.
the country studies demonstrate the strong link between overall
economic growth and the speed of poverty reduction. the incidence
of poverty fell in the 11 countries that experienced significant growth
during the period, and rose in the three countries that saw little or no
growth (Zambia, Indonesia and Romania). on average, a 1 percent
increase in GDP per capita for these countries reduced poverty by 1.7
percent during this period (figure 1). the reduction in poverty was particularly
spectacular in Vietnam, where poverty fell by 7.8 percent a year
between 1993 and 2002, halving the poverty rate from 58 percent to
29 percent. other countries with impressive poverty reductions include
el Salvador, Uganda, Ghana, India and tunisia, each with declines of
3 to 6 percent a year.
The country
studies
demonstrate
the strong link
between overall
economic
growth and the
speed of poverty
reduction
In growing countries, most of the absolute reduction in poverty was
in rural areas, where the majority of poor households lived. the proportional
decline in poverty rates was more marked, however, in these
countries’ urban areas, characterized by higher growth. For instance,
trade liberalization, market-oriented reforms, export incentives and
massive increases in infrastructure and education helped to reduce urban
poverty by 11 percent a year in Vietnam between 1993 and 2002.
In the Sub-Saharan countries, where most agricultural growth came
from export crops, the deepest cuts in poverty were for those growing
them (cotton in Burkina Faso, coffee and cotton in Uganda, cocoa in
Ghana). But given the predominance of poor households in producing
foodcrops, they accounted for the greatest share of poverty reduction
even in these countries.
Driving these overall reductions in poverty was the rebound in
growth that began for most of the countries in the mid-1990s. the
median GDP growth rate for the 14 countries was 2.4 percent a year
between 1996 and 2003. the success of macro stabilization measures
was integral to this recovery in many of them, particularly those initially
underperforming (Uganda, Senegal, Bolivia, and Ghana). efforts to
cut inflation and reduce external and internal imbalances (including
competitive exchange rates) were particularly effective in stimulating
nonagricultural growth, which grew on average by 3.1 percent in the
1990s and early 2000s, compared with 0.6 percent for agriculture. Price
liberalization and trade reforms also stimulated exports of manufactures
and agricultural products for the asian and several of the african countries
(Burkina Faso, Ghana and Uganda).
Improved structural and sectoral policies also contributed to higher
growth. the devaluation of the CFa franc in Senegal stimulated higher
levels of investment and strong urban growth. high levels of infrastructure
spending in Indonesia, Vietnam and Bangladesh fueled agricultural
and nonfarm growth, particularly in rural areas. and better human development
outcomes (health and education) in most countries outside
africa (where aIDS resulted in reversals on several dimensions), improved
their growth prospects. Rising capital inflows from foreign direct
investment (albeit from a very low base), aid (particularly in the african
countries) and remittances also fostered higher growth in the 1990s.
while the power of growth in reducing poverty is undeniable, the
experience of the 14 countries in this study also shows that growth
was more powerful in reducing poverty in some countries than others.
Greater poverty reduction was observed where policies were in place to
enhance the capacity of poor people to participate in growth. Several
of these policies are the same as those required to foster higher growth.
exeCutive summary—Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries 3
Greater poverty
reduction
was observed
where policies
were in place
to enhance
the capacity
of poor people
to participate
in growth
4 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
For example, trade liberalization and incentives for manufacturing enterprises
helped expand employment opportunities for semiskilled and
unskilled labor (and particularly women) in Bangladesh, el Salvador,
tunisia and Vietnam. the liberalization of imports and marketing of
agricultural inputs allowed poorer Bangladeshi farmers to expand their
use of low-cost irrigation pumps, in turn facilitating their use of higher
yielding Green Revolution technology. Coffee sector reforms at a time
of rising world prices helped lift a significant number of rural Uganda
households out of poverty.
the country studies also illustrate the value of viewing growth
through a pro-poor lens for analyzing and addressing the constraints
that poor households face in participating in growth.1 Depending on
the country circumstances, this may mean that access to electricity and
secondary education should increase not only in the capital city but
also in small towns, peri-urban areas and villages. In other contexts,
it may call for an emphasis on strengthening institutions that help to
deliver titles that build on customary tenure systems. these interventions
increase the quantity and quality of poor people’s productive
assets and their ability to participate on an equal footing in product
and factor markets. In so doing, they help poor households to increase
their agricultural and nonagricultural employment (both wages and
self-employment) and benefit from rising earnings associated with the
growth process.
Increasing the participation of poor households in growth
Making agricultural activities more productive
Because the vast majority of poor people live in rural areas and draw
their livelihoods from agriculture, the discussion begins with factors
that can raise the incomes of poor people who continue to rely on
agriculture. Bangladesh and Uganda typify some of the policies and
constraints that affected the agricultural earnings of poor farmers. In
Bangladesh liberalizing imports of agricultural inputs and machinery
improved access to low-cost irrigation, which along with greater investments
in flood infrastructure and safety net programs, led many poorer
farmers to adopt Green Revolution technology, raising their productivity
and incomes. In Uganda poorer farmers benefited from rising coffee
prices in the mid-1990s. But since the late 1990s agricultural earnings
have stagnated, particularly for poor farmers, and rural poverty reduction
has slowed significantly. what constrains earnings growth for poor
farmers? thin input markets, despite liberalization. extension and microfinance
services that are still accessible mainly to larger farmers. and
The country
studies
illustrate the
value of viewing
growth through
a pro-poor lens
land market and use rights that remain unclear, reducing incentives for
smallholder farmers to invest.
Five policy interventions were important in helping to raise the agricultural
earnings of poor households in the 1990s.
• Improving market access and lowering transaction costs.
• Strengthening property rights for land.
• Creating an incentive framework that benefits all farmers.
• expanding the technology available to smallholder producers.
• helping poorer and smaller producers deal with risk.
among the countries where agricultural earnings increased for the
poor, these policies were not in place to the same degree. and not all of
them had the same effect on increasing the ability of the poor to participate
in growth, reflecting the different initial conditions and other
influences in individual countries.
Improving market access and lowering transaction costs were essential in
Indonesia, Bangladesh and parts of Vietnam for increasing the agricultural
earnings of smaller and poor farmers. Market access for them was
facilitated by significant investments in rural roads and marketplaces
(often implemented under food for work programs), by high population
densities and by the fact that smallholder export and foodcrops were often
the same (rice). But high transaction costs did constrain agricultural
earnings in the more remote regions of the asian and latin american
countries, where rural poverty is disproportionately high (such as the
upland regions of Vietnam, northeast Brazil and Bolivia). In some of
these countries, policy options could include providing skills that would
enable the poor to profit from economic opportunities elsewhere.
among the low income african countries in the sample, high transaction
costs and low market access were among the most important constraints
on expanding agricultural earnings, especially for small farmers
and those in remote areas. with food markets in africa expected to
be the fastest growing of all agricultural markets in the continent over
the next 20 years (Commission for africa 2005), it will be important
to link rural farmers to local and regional markets with better infrastructure
and marketing associations. Contract farming with nGos
and the private sector has facilitated market access in several african
countries, particularly when complemented by organized involvement
at the grassroots.
Strengthening property rights for land improved the incentives to increase
production and diversify into higher value crops in Vietnam.
In 1988 land was decollectivized, and under the 1993 land law certificates
of use were issued to all rural households, stimulating the intensification
and diversification of agricultural production into higher
exeCutive summary—Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries 5
Five policy
interventions
were important
in helping
to raise the
agricultural
earnings of
poor households
in the 1990s
6 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
value-added crops. For the poorer farmers in the african case studies,
clear tenure and transparent land markets were important. weak
land market institutions—often reflecting the partial implementation
of land laws (Uganda, Burkina Faso), the lack of full transparency in
local land management decisions (Zambia) and the difficulties in gaining
access to land for non-community members (Ghana)—were key
constraints on the ability of all farmers, but particularly poorer farmers,
to invest in their land. the lack of secure tenure and of legally recognized
ownership rights, particularly for inheritance, affected poor rural
women in the african countries, who often are the primary producers
of foodcrops. In many african countries, improving the security of land
tenure for poorer farmers will require developing formal systems that
strengthen and complement customary land practices.
In Brazil and Bolivia, access to land is a major issue because of very
unequal land distributions. large-scale land reform is not politically viable,
but expanding the access of smallholders and poorer farmers to
long-term financing, and in some cases grants for land purchases, have
been successful. In Bangladesh and India continuing restrictions on land
rental markets to protect ownership rights make it difficult and costly for
smaller farmers (particularly women and the landless) to rent land. In Indonesia
land rights remain fairly undefined at the local level, particularly
for forest (land records cover only 20 percent of all land in Indonesia).
opaque and costly systems of land administration and allocation in rural
Indonesia are serious obstacles to expanding agricultural earnings, particularly
for poorer farmers (Deininger and Zakout 2004).
Creating an incentive framework that benefits all farmers was an important
part of the structural reforms by the african countries, Bangladesh,
Vietnam and Romania. the impact has varied depending on
the size of production units, access to capital, technical assistance, and
markets (or transaction costs) and the crops they grow. trade liberalization,
along with land reform, promoted Vietnam’s rapid emergence as a
major world exporter of rice and coffee in the 1990s, greatly benefiting
smallholders. trade liberalization in Bangladesh facilitated imports of
low-cost inputs, increasing their use by poor farmers. Foodcrop farmers
in africa generally benefited less than export crop farmers, whose
poverty rates fell sharply. But except for coffee producers in Uganda,
export farmers tended to make up a small share of the total and were
mainly the better-off. the private sector often did not fill the void left by
reforms in foodcrop marketing, leaving many poor producers in remote
areas of africa without market access.
Subsidies and protection in India, Indonesia and tunisia characterized
agricultural production, redirecting public resources and incentives
Creating an
incentive
framework
that benefits all
farmers was an
important part
of the structural
reforms by
the African
countries
away from higher value production toward less labor-intensive basic
food grains. In India the reform of agricultural subsidies has been diffi-
cult, in large part because of their political appeal (keefer and khemani
2003). In Indonesia the tariff on rice imports raised prices for rice producers
(many of them are smallholders and poorer farmers) but hurt rice
consumers and slowed poverty reduction. But in reforming agriculture
it will be important to consider the transition costs to small farmers:
they may receive only a small share of total subsidies, but these subsidies
are a significant share of their total income. and in implementing trade
and price reforms more generally, it will be important to understand
how they will affect different types of households and to provide poorer
households with roads, financial services and marketing associations so
that they can take advantage of the new opportunities.
Expanding the technology available to smallholder producers was a critical
driver for the Green Revolution to raise agricultural earnings in asia.
In Indonesia Green Revolution technology and massive investments in
agriculture catalyzed high rates of pro-poor growth from the 1960s to
the 1980s. In Sub-Saharan africa, the lack of adequate technologies for
arid climates was a severe constraint on producers, particularly those
in foodcrops, where the poor are concentrated. Increasing financial
support to african research institutions and improving the delivery of
extension services to food crop farmers; and in particular women with
private firms and nGos, could lift agricultural earnings for poorer
farmers.
Helping poorer and smaller producers deal with risk has stimulated
the adoption of higher yielding agricultural techniques. Investments in
flood infrastructure and flood season safety nets for poorer farmers in
Bangladesh (along with greater access to private irrigation) reduced risk
and created incentives for diversification. Information and communication
technologies can provide smallholders with market information
(mobile phones in Uganda). and improving access to market storage
facilities can help to smooth seasonal fluctuations (Burkina Faso). In
general, expanding the use of targeted safety net programs (where administrative
capacity exists or can be reinforced) would help avoid severe
deprivation from output and price variations and encourage farmers to
adopt riskier technologies that offer higher returns.
Taking advantage of nonagricultural and urban employment
opportunities
Urbanization is continuing at a fast pace. Understanding the factors
that can allow poor households to take advantage of nonagricultural
jobs in rural areas and job opportunities in urban areas is crucial for a
exeCutive summary—Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries 7
Helping poorer
and smaller
producers deal
with risk has
stimulated the
adoption of
higher yielding
agricultural
techniques
8 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
pro-poor growth strategy. In Vietnam trade liberalization and export
promotion in labor-intensive manufacturing—combined with rising
domestic demand stimulated in part by fairly high rates of agricultural
growth—increased nonagricultural employment and earnings for poor
households in urban and more connected rural areas. In Burkina Faso
informal employment expanded rapidly in services, but earnings fell,
due to insufficient demand, reflecting slow agricultural growth, a weak
investment climate and difficulties in accessing international markets.
More generally, the country cases underscored four broad policy
options to enhance access to nonagricultural earnings for poor
households.
• Improving the investment climate.
• expanding access to secondary and girls’ education.
• Designing labor market regulations to create attractive employment
opportunities.
• Increasing access to infrastructure.
as with policies to expand agricultural earnings for the poor, the
relative priorities and the appropriate design and scope of these policy
options vary across countries.
Improving the investment climate stimulated growth, influencing the
size of the formal sector and the composition of formal employment. In
Vietnam, Bangladesh and tunisia, investment climate improvements,
trade liberalization and special incentives for manufacturing industries
significantly increased unskilled manufacturing employment, particularly
for women. In Senegal, rising urban employment reflected high
levels of investment, a competitive exchange rate and a fairly good investment
climate. By contrast, policy uncertainty and macro instability
constrained nonagricultural investment and employment in Zambia,
increasing urban poverty. In Ghana, private investment remained low
(undermined in part by persistently high inflation and a poor investment
climate), causing manufacturing employment to contract in the
late 1990s.
Expanding access to secondary and girls’ education has become more
important with the rising skill bias of nonagricultural employment. In
India and Brazil poor educational outcomes reduced growth among
different states and the impact of that growth on poverty reduction.
Female literacy, also important in reducing poverty, was the most important
determinant of interstate differences in the efficiency of nonfarm
growth in reducing poverty in India (Ravallion and Datt 1996).
educational differences were associated with rising inequality in Bolivia
and Uganda: those with more education were better placed to take
the more attractive nonagricultural jobs. although most of the african
The country
cases
underscored
four policy
options to
enhance
access to
nonagricultural
earnings for
poor households
countries in the sample now have near-universal primary school enrollment,
secondary enrollments hardly increased, greatly constraining
the development of nonagricultural activities. In tracking educational
outcomes, it is also important to examine quality and transparency.
In Uganda the massive increases in primary school enrollments in the
1990s undermined quality. In addition, there was extensive leakage of
educational funds—leakages since reduced by increasing the transparency
of budget management, particularly at local levels.
Designing labor market regulations to create attractive formal employment
for poor workers helps expand their nonagricultural earnings, particularly
in countries with fast growth. labor market regulations, often
designed to protect the interests of poor workers, can restrict formal
labor markets and the access of poor workers. In India states with “proworker”
legislation recorded lower growth rates and less efficiency in
reducing poverty. In Bolivia and Romania “pro-worker” regulations,
encouraged by unions and the economic elite, kept employment in the
formal labor market below levels otherwise possible. During Romania’s
negative growth period, workers were forced to return to agriculture
in large part because labor markets were inflexible, due to high payroll
taxes, a cumbersome bureaucracy and tight labor regulations (especially
for unemployment benefits and the minimum wage). By contrast, Indonesia’s
high degree of labor market flexibility during the Suharto years
promoted formal employment and labor-intensive growth. But since the
1997 asian crisis, minimum wage increases prompted by union activity
have left almost all employment growth to the informal sector, at wages
below those in the formal sector.
three caveats: First, labor market regulations are only one of a set of
factors that affect the investment climate and the willingness of a firm
to formalize. other critical constraints include policy uncertainty, fiscal
burdens, cost of finance, corruption and the quality of courts (world
Bank 2005c) (see earlier discussion on investment climate, p. 8). Second,
loosening labor market regulations in some regions, particularly africa,
may have little impact on labor markets, especially if employment is
mainly in agriculture (Burkina Faso). third, labor market regulations,
though imperfect, constitute a form of social protection. the extent
of labor market regulation needs to reflect a balance between workers’
needs and employers’ needs, a balance that hangs on a country’s labor
market conditions and level of development.
Increasing access to infrastructure (especially roads combined with
electricity) linking rural areas to small towns and urban centers, along
with strong nonagricultural growth, contributed to rising informal sector
employment in rural Bangladesh, India, Vietnam and el Salvador.
exeCutive summary—Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries 9
Labor market
regulations can
restrict formal
labor markets
and the access
of poor workers
to these markets
10 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
In contrast, the lack of infrastructure in africa constrained access to
attractive informal employment in rural areas, and kept the rural poor
engaged in more traditional and lower return nonfarm activities linked
to agriculture. as such, lifting infrastructure constraints to improve
market access, as well as increasing access to electricity and education
in high density rural areas and small towns, may raise nonagricultural
earnings for the poor. But improving access to infrastructure requires
more than expanding public investments—it also requires higher institutional
quality. Poor institutions in Uganda may have prevented
improvements to the power infrastructure (keefer 2000).
Pro-poor growth strategies that reflect country conditions
this summary identifies several policies that can help poor households
take advantage of growth opportunities. the analysis also underscores
that the priority-setting and phasing of these policies will differ across
countries—according to their conditions. Successful pro-poor growth
strategies need to be built on a thorough analysis of what limits the
participation of poor households in the growth process in specific countries.
ten lines of enquiry for such analysis are attached to the report
(annex 1).
as with growth strategies, the binding constraints that need to be
addressed to enhance the ability of poor people to participate in growth
will vary depending on country conditions. Six characteristics that were
particularly relevant among the case studies are discussed below.
• Population density and its degree of urbanization. a country’s population
density and degree of urbanization determine the extent
to which transaction costs and remoteness preclude rural households
from participating in growth and the relative importance
of a targeted infrastructure strategy. For example, in Bangladesh
transaction costs are less of a constraint than in Uganda, where
the population density is much lower. Variations in population
density within countries also influence regional priorities. In
Vietnam transaction cost may not be a major constraint for rural
entrepreneurs in the Southwest, but they are for producers in the
remote northern mountain region.
• Asset and income inequality. the initial asset and income inequality
influences the poverty-reducing impact of future growth. It
may also reveal gender or ethnic discrimination or other inequality
traps that keep certain groups from having an equal footing in
factor or input markets.
• Importance of agriculture. the relative importance of agriculture in
the economy and the workforce determines the need to raise agri-
Successful propoor
growth
strategies need
to be built on
a thorough
analysis of
what limits the
participation of
poor households
in the growth
process
cultural earnings or encourage mobility. For example, in Uganda
where 90 percent of poor households are in rural areas and 80
percent of the workforce is engaged in agriculture, promoting sectoral
growth for smallholders and sectoral mobility will be central
to the country’s pro-poor growth strategy.
• Climate in and across sectors. Climatic instability affects agricultural
earnings and the need for risk management initiatives to
protect poor farmers and to encourage their investments in higher
yielding but riskier activities.
• Fertility. the fertility rate indicates how women, particularly
poorer women (since they tend to have higher birth rates), can
participate in the workforce. where the fertility rate remains high,
as for most of Sub-Saharan africa, countries should accelerate
girls’ education.
• Institutions. the quality and capacity of institutions (accountability,
transparency) for service delivery affect how much public
investments can be relied upon to link the poor to growth.
the experience of the 14 countries in the 1990s underscores three areas
of future research to help policymakers understand how to increase
the participation of poor households in growth and accelerate poverty
reduction.
• First, movement from agricultural to nonagricultural employment
was important in raising the incomes of poor households in many
countries, but there is also evidence that the more educated, better
connected workers were more successful in this regard. Understanding
how sectoral mobility might be enhanced is an important
area for further research.
• Second, the impact of growth was uneven across regions within
countries. Understanding how to craft public investment strategies
that can address subregional growth and poverty is another
important area for further analysis. the findings may differ for
low and middle income countries and could be particularly important
for countries with decentralized governments.
• third, political economy considerations often affect the distributional
outcomes of structural and investment policies, at times at
the expense of poor households. Understanding how to make public
policy to enhance the ability of the poor to participate in and influence
government processes is also an area for further exploration.
the 14 country studies give us useful insights on how to better integrate
short-term and long-term policies to increase the impact of growth
on poverty reduction. while policymakers cannot systematically “trade
less growth for more equity,” they can and should focus on countryexeCutive
summary—Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries 11
The country
studies give us
useful insights
on how to better
integrate shortterm
and longterm
policies
to increase
the impact
of growth
on poverty
reduction
12 Pro-Poor Growth in the 1990s: Lessons and insiGhts from 14 Countries
specific interventions that may make growth more poverty-reducing.
ensuring that national planning and strategic processes, such as poverty
reduction strategies in low-income countries, take more fully into
account the factors discussed here, and how they apply to different
countries, will be a key ingredient for reducing poverty more rapidly in
the coming decade.
Note
1. these messages are broadly similar to the findings of the 2006 World Development
Report, “equity and Development,” which calls for growth to increase
the opportunities of the poor, using a broader definition of opportunities
than this study to include asset endowments (including human capital assets),
wealth and power, market access and process fairness (world Bank 2005e).